Policy Options of Capital Flows to India

Policy Implications of Capital Inflows in India

by Sachin Kumar*,

- Published in Journal of Advances and Scholarly Researches in Allied Education, E-ISSN: 2230-7540

Volume 5, Issue No. 9, Jan 2013, Pages 0 - 0 (0)

Published by: Ignited Minds Journals


ABSTRACT

Existing studiesreveals that the huge surge in international capital flows since early 1990shas created unprecedented opportunities for the developing countries like Indiato achieve accelerated economic growth. International financial institutions routinely advise developingcountries to adopt policy regimes that encourage capital inflows. Since the introductionof the reform process in the early 1990s, India has witnessed a significantincrease in capital inflows. The size of net capital inflows to India increasedfrom US $ 7.1 billion in 1990-91 to US $ 108.0 billion in 2007-08. Today, Indiahas one of the highest net capital inflows among the EMEs of Asia. Capitalinflows, however, not an unmitigated blessing. The main danger posed by largeand volatile capital inflows is that they may destabilize macroeconomicmanagement. As evident, the intensified pressures due to large and volatile capitalflows in India in the recent period in an atmosphere of global uncertaintieshas posed new challenges for monetary and exchange rate management. The presentpaper elaborates on various aspects of the capital inflows to India and theirpolicy implications.

KEYWORD

capital flows, developing countries, economic growth, policy regimes, capital inflows

Research Scholar, Singhania, University, Rajasthan, India Abstract: Existing studies reveals that the huge surge in international capital flows since early 1990s has created unprecedented opportunities for the developing countries like India to achieve accelerated economic growth. International financial institutions routinely advise developing countries to adopt policy regimes that encourage capital inflows. Since the introduction of the reform process in the early 1990s, India has witnessed a significant increase in capital inflows. The size of net capital inflows to India increased from US $ 7.1 billion in 1990-91 to US $ 108.0 billion in 2007-08. Today, India has one of the highest net capital inflows among the EMEs of Asia. Capital inflows, however, not an unmitigated blessing. The main danger posed by large and volatile capital inflows is that they may destabilize macroeconomic management. As evident, the intensified pressures due to large and volatile capital flows in India in the recent period in an atmosphere of global uncertainties has posed new challenges for monetary and exchange rate management. The present paper elaborates on various aspects of the capital inflows to India and their policy implications. Key words: Capital inflows, policy, exchange rate, India.

--------------------------♦--------------------------

1. INTRODUCTION Economy, regardless of its level of development. For the developed countries it is necessary to support sustain- able development. For the developing countries, it is used to increase accumulation and rate of investments to create conditions for more intensive economic growth. For the transition countries [A transition country or transi- tional economy is an economy, which is changing from a centrally planned economy to a free market. Transition economies undergo economic liberalization (letting mar- ket forces set prices and lowering trade barriers), macro- economic stabilization where immediate high inflation is brought under control, and restructuring and privatization in order to create a financial sector and move from public to private ownership of resources], it is useful to carry out the reforms and cross to open economy (Edwards; Solow, 1956), to cross the past long term problems and to create conditions for stable and continuous growth of GDP (Razin, 2001), as well as integration in world eco- nomy (Boskovska, 2006; Harris and Gurel, 1986; Lensik, 1999). But, to realize the potential exist in the developing JEL Codes: F2; F21; F31; G01; G28. countries, foreign capital plays a very crucial role. Capital inflow [Capital inflow includes Foreign Direct Investment (FDI), Foreign Portfolio Investment (FPI), External Commercial Borrowing (ECBs), NRI Deposits and Social Deposits Schemes dominated that capital account] can help developing countries with economic development by furnishing them with necessary capital and technology. Capital flows contribute in filling the resource gap in countries where domestic savings are inadequate to finance investment. Capital inflows allow the recipient country to invest and consume more than it produces when the marginal productivity of capital with in its borders is higher than in the capital-rich regions of the world. Capital inflows facilitate the attainment of the millennium development goals (MDGs) and the objective of national economic, empowerment and development strategy (NEEDs). As the economy becomes more open and integrated with the rest of the world, capital flows will contribute significantly to the transformation of the developing economy (Levin, 2001). Added to this, capital inflows are necessary for macroeconomic stability as capital inflows affect a wide range of macro economic variables such as exchange rates, interest rates, foreign exchange reserves, domestic monetary conditions as well as saving and investments. Some commonly obser- ved effects of the capital inflows that have been docu- mented in the recent studies (Calvo et al., 1994; Calvo and Reinhart, 2000; Hutchison, 2002 Schneider and Tornell, 2004; Ito, 2006; Jitter, 2003; Kaminsky, 2003 amongst others) include real exchange rate appreciation, stock market and real estate boom, reserve accumu-

Available online at www.ignited.in Page 2

E-Mail: ignitedmoffice@gmail.com

lation, monetary expansion as well as effect on produc- tion and consumption. The paper has been arranged as follows: Section 1 provides an overview of foreign capital flows in the deve- loping countries. Section 2 highlights composition of capi- tal inflows in India. Section 3 gives an insight of govern- ment regulations to manage foreign capital in India. Section 4 highlights the some of the major issues and challenges for the central banks and suggests the policy options for foreign capital management. In the end, paper concludes with the future outlook. 1. Capital inflows in the developing countries Capital flow in the forms of portfolio and foreign direct investment is not only an engine for globalization but also a catalyst for economic development for developing countries (Stiglitz and Andrew, 1981; Tesar, 1991; Tobin, 1983; Hutchision and Noy, 2006; Wade and Veneroso, 1998). However, capital flow from developed countries to developing countries has been skewed (Aghion et al., 2001). Only selected Asian and Latin American countries received capital from developed countries in a large scale. Most sub-Saharan African countries, which urg- ently needed foreign capital for economic betterment, have been excluded from globalized investment. Data indicate that in most countries, resurgence in economic growth and a marked accumulation of international reser- ves accompany the increased capital inflows. In Asia, measured either in current or constant US dollars; net private capital (Private equity is an asset class consisting of equity securities in operating companies that are not publicly traded on a stock exchange. Investments in pri- vate equity most often involve either an investment of capital into an operating company or the acquisition of an operating company. Capital for private equity is raised primarily from institutional investors. There is a wide array of types and styles of private equity and the term private equity has different connotations in different countries) inflows in the mid 1990s were unprecedented in terms of the size of the flow to emerging markets in the post-war period (Table 1). Table 1 indicates that, in the mid-1990s inflows to Asia were larger (Mohamed, 2003), in both nominal and real terms, than the recycled petrodollar (In recent years, oil- exporting countries have experienced windfall gains with the rise in the price of oil. A look at how oil exporters “recycle” their revenues reveals that roughly half of the petrodollar windfall has gone to purchase foreign goods, especially from Europe and China, while the remainder has been invested in foreign assets. Although it is difficult to determine where the funds are first invested, the evi- dence suggests that the bulk is ending up, directly or indirectly, in the United States) inflows to Latin America in the late 1970s and early 1980s. The flows to Asia were also large relative to the size of the recipient economies: while capital inflows in 1996 to the five affected Asian countries – Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, the Philippines and Thailand – were less than half the size of flows into the United States, these countries’ combined economies, credit systems and share markets were but a tenth of the size of those of the United States (Grenville, 1998). In the 1990s, foreign direct investment (Foreign direct invest- ment is investment of foreign assets into domestic struc- tures, equipment, and organizations. It does not include foreign investment into the stock markets. Foreign direct investment is thought to be more useful to a country than investments in the equity of its companies because equity investments are potentially "hot money" which can leave at the first sign of trouble, whereas FDI is durable and generally useful whether things go well or badly) (FDI) to emerging markets remained the most stable source of capital inflows, even at the peak of the financial crisis, while bank loans were the most volatile and underwent the most violent reversal (Arellano and Mendoza, 2002). Table 2 indicates that net capital flows to the developing countries have increased tremendously between 2000 - 2007. Net private direct investment has also registered rapid growth, whereas net private portfolio investment has remained highly volatile during the same period periods. Net other private capital flows registered positive growth starting from 2002 but again remained highly volatile. The capital inflows into Asia through purchases of equities have become larger and more volatile over the years. The scale of the pullback by foreign investors from Asian equities in episodes of global volatility in equity markets has gotten larger over the years, as shown in Figure 1. Note: Shaded areas refer to seven episodes of rising volatility since 1998: the Russian default (August 1998), September 11, 2001, June-July 2002, the May 2006 sell- off, the February 2007 sell-off, the Bear Stern hedge fund woes in August 2007 and the subprime –related sell-off in November 2007. Data related to Korea, Indonesia, Taipei,

Available online at www.ignited.in Page 3

E-Mail: ignitedmoffice@gmail.com

China and Thailand in billion US $ Source: Bloomberg; Korean Stock Exchange, Philippines Stock Exchange and BIS calculations. The bouts of disinvestment that have occurred since the summer of 2007 have been unprecedented. In the face of losses on mortgage securities, liquidity blockages in major money markets and prospects for decelerating growth, foreign investors liquidated over US$12 billion in August and November in six Asian markets with daily transaction reporting. These liquidations have reached such levels notwithstanding the fact that global volatility

Available online at www.ignited.in Page 4

E-Mail: ignitedmoffice@gmail.com

(as measured by the VIX index of option prices on the Standard and Poor’s index of US equities) has not clim- bed to the levels reached earlier in the decade or at the time of the LTCM [Long-Term Capital Management (LTCM) was a U.S. hedge fund which used trading strategies such as fixed income arbitrage, statistical arbritage, and pairs trading, combined with high leverage. It failed spectacularly in the late 1990s, leading to a massive bailout by other major banks and investment houses, which were supervised by the Federal Reserve. LTCM was founded in 1994 by John Meriwether, the former vice-chairman and head of bond trading at Salomon Brothers. Board of directors’ members included Myron Scholes and Robert C. Merton, who shared the 1997 Nobel Prize in economic science. Initially enor- mously successful with annualized returns of over 40% (after fees) in its first years, in 1998 it lost $4.6 billion in less than four months following the Russian financial crisis and became a prominent example of the risk poten- tial in the hedge fund industry. The fund folded in early 2000] and Russian defaults [The Russian financial crisis (also called "Ruble crisis") hit Russia on 17 August 1998. It was triggered by the Asian financial crisis, which started in July 1997. During the ensuing decline in world commodity prices, countries heavily dependent on the export of raw materials were among those most severely hit. Petroleum, natural gas, metals, and timber accounted for more than 80% of Russian exports, leaving the coun- try vulnerable to swings in world prices. Oil was also a majorsource of government tax revenue]. Even before thismost recent episode, these flows have drawn muchmarket commentary and such interest led a number ofstock exchanges to release daily data on non-residentflows. This has resulted in a number of carefustudies that have shed much light on the relationshipbetween capital flows and equity prices. 2. Composition of capital inflows in India International capital flow such as direct and portfolioflows has huge contribution to influence the economicbehavior of the developing countries positively. Prof.Krugman (1993) rightly pointed out; capital inflows play avery important role in capturing the benefits ofglobalization. Various studies (Buiter and Patel, 2006;Caballero, 2000) revealed that it is not so much thequantity but the quality of money that is making thedifference. Whereas, the old two-gap theory suggests[The two-gap model is an extension of the Harrod-Domar growth model. The second "gap" (in additionto the savings gap) is found by introducing foreign tradeand rephrasing the model such that: g = s/k + b/kSavings gap- domestic savings are inadequate tosupport the level of growth, which could be permittedgiven the import purchasing power of the economy andthe level of other resources Foreign exchange gap-

Available online at www.ignited.in Page 5

E-Mail: ignitedmoffice@gmail.com

import purchasing power conferred by the value of exports plus capital transfers may be inadequate to support the level of growth permitted by the level of domestic saving. The two-gap theory purports that investment and development are restricted by level of either domestic saving or import purchase capacity] that it is quantity of money that counts. Now researchers are conscious about the technological and managerial skills, the work culture, and the synergies accompanying capital flows that seem to give a lot more contribution to growth. Even with regard to portfolio flow from Foreign Insti- tutional Investors [FIIs (The term is used most commonly in India to refer to outside companies investing in the financial markets of India. International institutional investors must register with the Securities and Exchange Board of India to participate in the market. One of the major market regulations pertaining to FIIs involves placing limits on FII ownership in Indian companies)], the way in which FIIs assess market practices in stock exchanges have enhanced our own practice and skill among participants to global standards (Mohan, 2008). So, one has to look at the capital flows in a broader sense rather than as mere numbers and in any case the issue has to be evaluated in the country context. India is a developing country, like many other develo-ping countries, international capital flows has significant potential benefit on the Indian economy (Dash and Sum- anjeet, 2008). Under the liberalized foreign exchange transactions regime, the results were dramatic. The lib- eralization of the portfolio investment led to a surge in inflow of capital for investment (Mody and Murshid, 2002) in the primary and secondary market (Dash and Sumanjeet, 2005) for Indian equity and corporate (and subsequently sovereign) bond market. The composition of capital inflow has changed significantly over the years (Gopinath, 2004). Dependence on aid has vanished and foreign direct investment (FDI), foreign portfolio invest- ment [FPI (Portfolio Investment represents passive holdings of securities such as foreign stocks, bonds, or other financial assets, none of which entails active mana- gement or control of the securities' issuer by the investor; where such control exists, it is known as foreign direct investment. Some examples of portfolio investment are: purchase of shares in a foreign company, purchase of bonds issued by a foreign government and acquisition of assets in a foreign country)], external commercial borro- wings [ECB {External Commercial borrowing (ECB) is a term used to refer to commercial loans availed from non- resident lenders with a minimum average maturity of 3 years in the form of bank loans, buyers credit, suppliers credit, securitized instruments (e.g. floating rate notes and fixed rate bonds). A company is free to raise ECB from any internationally recognized source such as banks, export credit agencies, suppliers of equipment, foreign collaborators, foreign equity-holders, international capital markets etc. However, offers from unrecognized sources are not entertained. ECB can be accessed under two routes, Automatic Route and Approval Route. Under the Automatic Route, the approval of Reserve Bank of India (RBI) or the Governments approval are not require- ed. However, in case of doubt regarding eligibility under the Automatic Route, applicants may take recourse to the Approval Route. The maximum amount of ECB that can be raised by an eligible borrower under the Automatic Route during one financial year is USD 500 million. NGOs engaged in micro finance activities have been permitted to raise ECB up to USD 5 million during a financial year for permitted end-use}] and nonresident Indians (NRI) deposits dominate the capital flows. Among these again, there has been a gradual shift away from debt components to equity flows (The proportion of non- debt has gone up from about 5% in the second half of the 1980). But, the period of 1990s show a radical transfor-

Available online at www.ignited.in Page 6

E-Mail: ignitedmoffice@gmail.com

mation in the nature of capital flow into India. From a mere absence of any capital flow till 1992 (expect those by non residents Indian), today such inflows represent a dominant proportion to total flows (Chakraborty, 2001). The official flow shows an external assistance, that is, grants and loans from bilateral and multilateral sources represented 75 - 80% flow till 1991. By 1994, this has come down to about 20% and has further fallen to below by 5% by late 1990’s. About 460 FIIs have been allowed to enter the Indian market and together have brought in more than US $ 14 billion GDR [Global Depository Receipt means any instrument in the form of a depository receipt or certificate created by the overseas depository bank outside India and issued to non- resident investors against the issue of ordinary shares or Foreign Currency Convertible Bonds of issuing company. Among the Indian Companies, Reliance Industries Ltd. was the first com- pany to raise funds through a GDR issue] (Global Depo- sitory Receipts) and ADR [An American Depositary Receipt (or ADR) represents the ownership in the shares of a foreign company trading on US financial markets. The stock of many non-US companies trades on US ex- changes through the use of ADRs. ADRs enable US investors to buy shares in foreign companies without undertaking cross-border transactions. ADRs carry prices in US dollars, pay dividends in US dollars, and can be traded like the shares of US-based companies] (Ameri- can Depository Receipts) floated by Indian corporate sector brought in the remaining portfolio inflows. Table 3 provides an overview of the total foreign capital that India attracted during the 1991-92 to 2007-08 period. As the Table shows, India has attracted about $22 billion in portfolio investments since 1993-94 and more than $18 billion in FDI. These portfolios flows began in 1993 when India attracted more than $5 billion in few months and continued at the level of $ 2-3 billion per year till the Asian crises. The year 1998 witnessed a marginal out flow from the Indian stock market but soon the inflows went back to the US $ 2-3 billion per year level. By the end of year 2004, India has attracted more than US $ 40 billion of foreign investment. Foreign capital inflows were highly volatile in the 2004-05 fiscal. However net inflow was almost same as 2003-04. But in next three years net capital inflows were increased significantly. In the year 2007-08, FDI reached at $ 32435 million. FPI and FII, which were at slide in the year 2006-07, reported a significant increase in the year 2007-08. In the fiscal year of 2006-2007, FDI inflows reported sharp and significant increase. Although FDI inflows are affected by when mega projects come into, the inflows between 2006 and 2007 based on the fiscal year show approximately 200% of growth that is compared to the previous year [U.S.A, U.K and Singapore hold 62% of the FDI inflows. These countries have much higher inflows of FDI in comparison with other countries. Moreover, U.S.A has been interes- ted in entry of Wal-Mart in India and Nuclear Agreement. U.S.A continuously has made a contribution to not only IT industry but also large number of entities in U.S is going to invest in the service sector afterwards. Singapore recently has been outstanding in real estate sector and accelerating to Indian investment. After the year of 2000, six countries have had over US$ 1 billion of FDI inflows

Available online at www.ignited.in Page 7

E-Mail: ignitedmoffice@gmail.com

and approximately 23 countries have been expanding their FDI equity over $0.1 billion so that relatively the amount of FDI inflows are not enough in real situation]. Again structure of foreign capital inflow is highly volatile in the current fiscal. India has received $14.6 billion FDI during April-August 2008. FDI to India surged to $2.56 billion in September, up 9% over the same month last year. But, since the beginning of year 2008, FIIs have till date sold $ 13.00 billon- a far cry from inflow of $17.23 and $8 billion in 2007. Table 4 depicts the outflow of capital from Indian market. FDI outflow was almost stagnant between 2002- 03 to 2005-06. But, FPI statistics shows sharp increasing trend. In fiscal 2001-02 where it was only $ 7.3 billion has touched the mark of $102.6 billion at the end of fiscal 2006-07. In 2008, there is sudden outflow of FIIs. Added to these FIIs inflow has also declined after April 2008. Table 5 indicates the sharp decline in FIIs inflow in India during 2008. However, FIIs are turning positive on India as thecalendar year is coming to an end. FIIs pumped in morethan Rs 1,629.30 Crore in the Indian stock market tilDecember 1, 2008, thus maintain a positive flow for thefirst half of the month after a long time. There have beenthree occasions this year when a month started with the net inflows, but ended with the net outflow. If we measure net flow of foreign capital in GDP, then netcapital flows stagnated at roughly 2.5% of GDP from1993 to 2000, and has since risen sharply to 5.4% ofGDP by 2007 (Table 6). This has partly reflected a rise in equity flows, which were encouraged by policy makers, and went from 0.25% of GDP in 1993 to 1.24% of GDP in 2000 to 1.87% of GDP in 2007. India's policy makers have believed that debt flows are dangerous, and at first, debt inflows dropped from 3% of GDP in 1993 to 0.9% of GDP in 2000. However, by 2007, debt inflows were back to 2.98% of GDP. 3. Current regulations to manage capital inflows in India Capital flows contribute in filling the resource gap incountry like India where the domestic savings are inade-quate to finance investment (Ghose, 2004; Dasgupta andRatha, 2000). Today, India requires approximately 500billion US $ investment in infrastructure sector alone inthe next 5 years for sustaining present growth rate ofapproximately 8 – 9%. This amount is around 2.5 times more than the 10th Plan. Added to this, already, severalinfrastructure projects have reportedly been shelved and indefinitely delayed. Such huge mobilization of resources is not possible from India’s internal resources (Mohan, 2008). Therefore, India need for capital in the form ofECBs and other foreign loans and aids. Keeping in viewthe growing requirements of foreign capital in India,Indian government has comp up with many policies andliberalized regulations to manage foreign capital in India.Some of the important and recent measures taken by Indian government to manage foreign investments in India are as under:

Available online at www.ignited.in Page 8

E-Mail: ignitedmoffice@gmail.com

Foreign direct investment FDI [FDI is widely recognized as a composite bundle of capital inflows, knowledge and technology transfer. Hence the impact of FDI on growth is expected to be manifold. (Chakraborthy and Peter, 2008)] is permitted under the Automatic Route in items/ activities in all sectors up to the sectoral caps except in certain sectors where investment is prohibited. Investments not permitted under the automatic route require approval from Foreign Investment Promotion Board (FIPB). The receipt of remittance has to be reported to RBI within 30 days from the date of receipt of funds and the issue of shares has to be reported to RBI within 30 days from the date of issue by the investee company. Advance against equity: An Indian company issuing shares to a person resident outside India can receive such amount in advance. The amount received has to be reported within 30 days from the date of receipt of funds. There is no provision on allotment of shares within a specified time. The banks can refund the amount received as advance, provided they are satisfied with the bonafides of the applicant and they are satisfied that no part of remittance represents interest on the funds received. Foreign portfolio investment FIIs: FIIs Investment by non-residents is permitted under the Portfolio Investment scheme to entities registered as FIIs and their sub accounts under SEBI [SEBI, establi- shed in 1988 and became a fully autonomous body by the year 1992 with defined responsibilities to cover both development and regulation of the market. SEBI has to be responsive to the needs of three groups, which con- stitute the market: the issuers of securities, the investors and the market intermediaries. SEBI has three functions rolled into one body quasi-legislative, quasi- judicial and and quasi-executive. It drafts regulations in its legislative capacity, it conducts investigation and enforcement ac- tion in itsexecutive function and it passes rulings and orders in its judicial capacity. Though this makes it very powerful, thereis an appeals process to create account- ability. There is aSecurities Appellate Tribunal which is a three member tribunal and is presently headed by a former Chief Justice of a High court - Mr. Justice NK Sodhi. A second appeal lies directly to the Supreme Court. SEBI has enjoyed success as a regulator by pushing systemic reforms aggressively and successively (e.g. the quick movementtowards making the markets electronic and paperless rolling settlement on T+2 basis). SEBI has been active in setting up the regulations as required under law] (FII) regulations. Investment by individual FIIs is subject to ceiling of 10% of the PUC (Pollution under Control) of the company and limit for aggregate FII investment is subject to limit of 24% of PUC of the company. This limit can be increased by the company subject to the sectoral limit permitted under the FDI policy. The transactions are subject to daily reporting by designated ADs (Authorized Dealers) to RBI for the purpose of monitoring the adherence to the ceiling for aggregate investments. NRIs: The investment by NRIs under the Portfolio Invest-ment Scheme is restricted to 5% by individual NRIs/ OCBs (not incorporated in Bangladesh and Pakistan) and 10% in aggregate (which can be increased to 24% by the company concerned). ADR/GDR: Indian companies are allowed to raise resources through issue of ADR/GDR and the eligibility of the issuer company is aligned with the requirements under the FDI policy. The issues of sponsored ADR/GDR require prior approval of ministry of finance. Foreign venture capital investors FVCIs (Foreign Venture Capital Investors) registered with SEBI are allowed to invest in units of venture capital funds any limit. FVCI investment in equity of Indian venture capital undertakings is also allowed. The limit for suchinvestments would be based on the sectoral limits under the FDI policy. FVCIs are also allowed to invest in debt instruments floated by the IVCUs (InVacare Corporation-US). There is no separate limit stipulated for investment in

Available online at www.ignited.in Page 9

E-Mail: ignitedmoffice@gmail.com

such instruments by FVCIs. External commercial borrowings Under the Automatic Route, ECB up to US $500 million per borrowing company per financial year is permitted only for foreign currency expenditure for permissible end- uses of ECB. Borrowers in infrastructure sector may avail ECB up to US $100 million for Rupee expenditure for permissible end-uses under the Approval Route. In case of other borrowers, the limit for Rupee expenditure for permissible end-uses under the Approval Route has been enhanced to US $50 million from earlier limit of US $20 million. Entities in the services sector, viz., hotels, hospi- tals and software companies have been allowed to avail ECB up to US $100 million, per financial year, for the purpose of import of capital goods under the Approval Route. The all-in-cost interest ceiling for borrowings with maturity of 3-5 years has been increased from 150 basis points over 6-month LIBOR [The LIBOR is the world's most widely used benchmark for short-term interest rates. It's important because it is the rate at which the world's most preferred borrowers are able to borrow money. It is also the rate upon which rates for less preferred borro- wers are based. For example, a multinational corporation with a very good credit rating may be able to borrow money for one year at LIBOR plus four or five points] (London Inter-bank Offered Rate) to 200 basis points over 6-month LIBOR. Similarly, the interest ceiling for loans maturing after 5 years period has been raised to 350 basis points over 6-month LIBOR from 250 basis points over 6-month LIBOR. Investment by NRIs in immovable properties The NRIs are permitted to freely acquire immoveable property (other than agricultural land, plantations and farmhouses). There are no restrictions regarding the number of such properties to be acquired. The only res- triction is that where the property is acquired out of inward remittances, the repatriation is restricted to principal amount for two residential properties. There is no such restriction in respect of commercial property. NRIs are also permitted to avail of housing loans for acquiring property in India and repayment of such loans by close relatives is also permitted. Added to the above-mentioned developments in the regulatory framework, recently the government of India has decided to restrict the entry of foreign investors (effective from 31st March 2009) in some sector like multi- brand retail, atomic energy, lottery, gambling and betting. Added to this, the government has also decided to restrictthe entry of foreign investors up to a specified level (Table 7). Note: FDI*+FII** up to 49% is automatic, beyond 49% requires the government approval Source: Complied by Researcher from various sources. In one stroke, the move will raise the level of foreign investment in a score of Indian companies and thereby crimp their ability to raise resources from overseas investors, especially in sectors with foreign investment caps. It will also allow overseas firm entry into restricted sectors like multi-brand retail and increase their expo-sures in sectors like the media where there is a limit on foreign investment. At present some sectors differentiate between foreign direct investment and foreign institutional investment while computing foreign investment. Sectorslike banking and DTH [DTH stands for Direct-To-Hometelevision. DTH is defined as the reception of satelliteprogrammes with a personal dish in an individual home. DTH does away with the need for the local cable operator and puts the broadcaster directly in touch with the consumer. Only cable operators can receive satellite programmes and they then distribute them to individual homes] broadcast services take into account both forms while calculating the foreign investment. But in sectors likeassets reconstruction only FDI is included. Under the new norms, all forms of overseas investment will be included while computing the foreign investment. 4. Issues and management of capital inflows in India The East Asian crisis of 1997-98 and the Mexican crisis of 1994 generated much concern among policy analysts regarding the role of macroeconomic policies in the management of capital inflows. A series of economic reform measures including liberalization of foreign capital inflows were initiated in India since the early nineties. After the liberalization of the exchange rate regime in the mid-1990s, the Reserve Bank had, therefore, to chart its own course of exchange rate management, learning from the contemporary experiences. There is now a well-laidout policy response to sudden changes in capital flows so

Available online at www.ignited.in Page 10

E-Mail: ignitedmoffice@gmail.com

as to stabilize markets: on demand-side, including monetary tightening and changes in the cost of import finance as well as on supply-side, including the Reserve Bank’s operations in the foreign exchange market and changes in the cost of delaying export proceeds (Figure 2). The Reserve Bank has been prepared to make sales and purchases of foreign currency in order to even out lumpy demand and supply in the relatively thin forex mar- ket and to smoothen jerky movements. However, such intervention is not governed by a predetermined target or band around the exchange rate (Jalan, 1999). The broad principles that have guided India after the Asian crisis of 1997 are: (i) careful monitoring and mana- gement of the exchange rate without a fixed or pre- announced target or a band; (ii) flexibility in the exchange rate together with ability to intervene, if and when necessary; (iii) a policy to build a higher level of foreign exchange reserves which takes into account not only anticipated current account deficits but also ‘liquidity at risk’ arising from unanticipated capital movements; and (iv) a judicious management of the capital account (Jalan, 2002). India’sexchange rate policy of focusing on managing volatility with no fixed rate target while allowing the underlying demand and supply conditions to deter- mine theexchange rate movements over a period in an orderly way has stood the test of time (Kohli, 2003). As a result of these timely and coordinated measures, India was successful in containing the contagion effect of the Asian crisis. In addition, safeguards developed over a period of time also helped in limiting the contagion; these included: low current account deficit; comfortable foreignexchange reserves; low level of short-term debt (Guptaand Sahay, 2003); and absence of asset price inflation or

Available online at www.ignited.in Page 11

E-Mail: ignitedmoffice@gmail.com

credit boom (Rangarajan, 2000). These positive features were the result of prudent policies pursued over the years notably, cap on external commercial borrowings with res- trictions on end-use, low exposure of banks to real estate and stock market, insulation from large intermediation of overseas capital by the banking sector, close monitoring of off-balance sheet items and tight legislative, regulatory and prudential control over non-bank entities (RBI, 2004). But, the incomplete sterilization [To ease the threat of currency appreciation or inflation, central banks often attempt what is known as the "sterilization" of capital flows. In a successful sterilization operation, the domestic component of the monetary base (bank reserves plus currency) is reduced to offset the reserve inflow, at least temporarily. In theory, this can be achieved in several ways, such as by encouraging private investment over- seas, or allowing foreigners to borrow from the local mar- ket. The classical form of sterilization, however, has been through the use of open market operations, that is, selling Treasury bills and other instruments to reduce the dome- stic component of the monetary base. The problem is that, in practice, such sterilization can be difficult to execute and sometimes even self-defeating, as an appa- rently successful operation may raise domestic interest rates and stimulate even greater capital inflows. Unfor- tunately, many developing countries also lack the tools available to run a classical sterilization policy, or find it simply too costly to do so. This is often the case where- ver the financial system is not fully liberalized] in the post- 2004 period has led to a pronounced acceleration of reserve money growth. During that period real interest rates have been very low when compared with other Asian countries. With low real rates, the stance of mone- tary policy has been expansionary. While the wholesale Price Index is widely watched in India, the Consumer Price Index is a bettermeasure of inflation. It has risen after 2004, and hasremained stubbornly high when com- pared with theaspirations of politicians and policymakers (Shah andPatnaik, 2008). Thus, even though capital inflows aresupplying much-needed financing to Indian corporatesand banks, they are also making monetary andexchange rate policy more challenging. In the recentperiod, in India, one of the most serious challenges to theconduct of monetary policy emerge from capital flows inview of the significantly higher volatility of such flows aswell as the fact that capital flows in gross term are muchhigher than those in net terms. Largely due to thebourgeoning foreign capital inflows, the rupee, duringApril 07 - January 08, appreciated against the dollar byanywhere between 11 - 15% comparison with the sameperiod last year. The reduction in inflows in the last twomonths arrested the double-digit appreciation witnesseduntil then (Table 8). Table indicates that buoyant capital inflows have push-ed up the value of the rupee [On 27th February rupee plunged to a record low of 51.17 per dollar, hit by impor- ters demand for dollar and share market losses after data showed to its weakest in nearly six years at the end of 2008. The partially convertible rupee closed at 51.10/12 per dollar, 1.3% weaker than 25th February close of 50.45/47 tackling its losses in 2009 to 4.7%], despite sig- nificant intervention by the Reserve Bank of India. This has raised concerns about India's competitiveness, par- ticularly in the labor-intensive textile, garment, and lea- ther industries (Sumanjeet, 2007). Capital inflows have also increased the money supply, which then raised inflationary pressure (Figure 3). In short, India is facing the policy challenges of the

Available online at www.ignited.in Page 12

E-Mail: ignitedmoffice@gmail.com

"impossible trinity": when there is free movement of capital, it is impossible to both target the exchange rate and maintain an independent monetary police (Richter, 2008). The other major macroeconomic problem caused by capital inflows is that they may build up a level of debt that the country finds it difficult to service on the con- tractually agreed terms, as happened throughout Latin America in 1982 (and again in Mexico in the early 1990s). This raises two issues: identifying how much debt a country can prudently take on and limiting borrowing to a prudent level when the market wants to lend more. A number of other problems are sometimes also mentioned as possible undesirable consequences of large capital inflows. Inflows may, for example, lead to a speculative bubble in the stock market (Figure 4) as various studies concluded that there is link between performance of stock market and flow of foreign capital (Henry, 2000; Beer andVaziri, 2004; Harris, 2004; Jobson and Korkie, 1981;Scholes, 1972; Wang and Shen 1999). Figure 4 clearlyshows that since the beginning of year 2008, ndian stockmarket is declining; however this dec- line is primarily dueto the outflow of FIIs from the Indian stock market(Sumanjeet, 2009). One undesirable consequence of sucha bubble is typically a decline in the local savings rate, asindividuals discover that their asset accumulationobjectives are being achieved without the need for anythingso tedious as abstaining from con- sumption. Anotherundesirable consequence can be a financial crisis, and thedanger of a recession, when the bubble bursts. Capitalinflows may also involve the loss of local control overeconomic decision-making: this is clear- est in the case ofmajority-owned direct investment, although direct

Available online at www.ignited.in Page 13

E-Mail: ignitedmoffice@gmail.com

investment, although direct investment carries offsetting benefits in terms of access to technology and markets, and the loss of control can in any event often be avoided through joint ventures. Problems may also arise to some degree in the case of portfolio equity investment, if concentrated share- holding is allowed, and even loans, where powerful foreign creditors (notably the IMF when times get difficult) expect to be consulted about the course of economic policy. Further, Large capital inflows, can impact macro- economic aggregates not only through the exchange rate, but also trade and monetary variables, according to Report of Reserve Bank of India. On the domestic front, the biggest challenge is the management of capital flows and the attendant implications for liquidity and overall stability. If there is a slowdown in capital inflows then it create many difficulties to the developing countries like lower growth rate, loss of forex reserves [According to data

Available online at www.ignited.in Page 14

E-Mail: ignitedmoffice@gmail.com

released by RBI, forex reserves dipped $165 million during the week ended February 20, 2009 to $249.5 billion largely because of revaluation of non-dollar assets such as Euro, Sterling Pound and the Japanese Yen vis- à-vis the US dollar. While foreign currency assets dipped $165 million, the value of gold and SDR-the currency with the IMF-remained unchanged during the week. The reserve with the IMF dipped $9 million during the week] (Figure 5), low employment opportunities [A number of studies, which consider this issue include – although not limited to – those by Jones (1984); Beladi and Marjit (1992); Chao and Yu (1994 and 1995); Marjit and Beladi (1996); Olarreaga (1996); Marjit et al. (1997); etc] etc. So, the large increase or decrease in capital inflows has generated the need of management of capital inflows in developing countries. To, manage capital inflows, emer- ging market economies choose among three policy options: i.) A larger current account deficit through trade liberaliza- tion or exchange rate appreciation. ii.) Restrictions on the capital inflows either through direct controls, a tax or a widening of exchange rate band. iii.) Offsetting capital outflows either through reserve accumulation or the promotion of private sector outflows. On the basis of above discussion on the issues relating tocapital inflows, the researcher suggest that management ofcapital inflows in India should be done through the followingpolicy options: i.) Sterilized intervention is very useful to counter undesi- rableexchange-rate movements. RBI occasionally inter- venes inthe foreign exchange market to curtail the ex- change ratevolatility. In India, intervention operations by the Reserve bankof India in the foreign exchange market are not essentially aphenomenon of the early 1990s, that is, post economicliberalization of 1992. However, inter- vention operations didincrease substantially since the introduction of the UnifiedExchange Rate System in March 1993 which made the IndianRupee convertible on the Current Account. Studies of foreignexchange inter- vention generally distinguish betweenintervention that does or does not change the monetary base.The former type is called unsterilized intervention while thelatter is referred to as sterilized intervention. Sterilizedintervene- tion keeps the money supply more or lessunchanged. Hence, unsterilized intervention is supposed tobe more effective in influencing the exchange rates. Centrabanks aim at sterilizing their intervention operations becauseunsterilized interventions go against the monetary policyobjectives pursued by the central banks. A related issue iswhether there should be sterilized intervention [It consists of adirect intervention of RBI in the foreign ex- change market byselling foreign exchange in order to prevent depreciation.Sterilized intervention policies can permanently influence theexchange rate under the assumption of imperfect substitution]and if so, the timing and quantum of such interventions. So,reduce steriliza- tion and concentrate on improving the creditpass through of monetary policy. The credit starvation ofsmall and medium enterprises must be eliminated. Adequateabsorption of foreign capital cannot be ensured by growth inservice exports alone. ii.) As far as the exchange rate is concerned, the large inflowof remittances and major and sustained growth in softwareexports coupled with capital inflows have the potential forpossible overvaluation of the currency and the resultanterosion of long term competitiveness of other traditionagoods sectors- a problem popularly known as Dutchdisease [Dutch disease is an economic concept that tries toexplain the apparent relationship between the exploitation ofnatural resources and a decline in the manufacturing sectorcombined with moral fallout. The theory is that an increase inrevenues from natural resources will de-industrialize a

Available online at www.ignited.in Page 15

E-Mail: ignitedmoffice@gmail.com

nation’s economy by raising the exchange rate, which makes the manufac- turing sector less competitive and public services entan- gled with business interests. However, it is extremely difficult to definitively say that Dutch disease is the cause of the decreasing manufacturing sector, since there are many other factors at play in the very complex global economy. While it most often refers to natural resource discovery, it can also refer to "any development that results in a large inflow of foreign currency, including a sharp surge in natural resource prices, foreign assis- tance, and foreign direct investment]. So, Exchange rate protectionism should be gradually eliminated and the currency should be allowed to appreciate in response to capital inflows. Protectioning the exchange sensitive sector should not be overriding concern of policy. iii.) For improving the position of foreign capital in India, trade liberalization should continue to stimulate absorp- tion of foreign exchange. But the process should be care- fully managed and monitored; otherwise surge in con- sumption imports will render CAD (Current Account Deficit) unsustainable. iv.) Shed the reluctance to check the torrent of FII, explore effective methods of restricting this flow rather than novel methods of sterilization. Due to the thinness of market (and its susceptibility to manipulation) large port- folio flows may cause equity bubbles. Reduction in non- FDI flows will reduce the need for large unproductive reserves. v.) Investment in infrastructure in general (and not only in telecom) must increase to boost domestic investment and attract FDI in manufacturing. vi.) A further challenge for policy in the context of fuller capital account openness will be to preserve the financial stability of the system as greater deregulation is done on capital outflows and on debt inflows. So, the approach to capital account convertibility should continue to be cautious until the crucial preconditions are fulfilled. vii.) Another aspect of greater capital market openness concerns the presence of foreign banks in India. With fuller capital convertibility and greater presence of foreign banks over time, a number of issues will arise. First, if these large global have emerged as a result of real eco- nomies of scale and scope, how will smaller national banks compete in countries like India, and will them- selves need to generate a larger international presence? Second, there is considerable discussion today on over- laps and potential conflicts betweenhome country regulators of foreign banks and host countryregulators: how will these be addressed and resolved in theyears to come? Third, given that operations in one countrysuch as India are typically small relative to the global opera-tions of these large banks, the attention of top manage- mentdevoted to any particular country is typically low.Consequently, any market or regulatory transgressionscommitted in one country by such a bank, which may have asignificant impact on banking or financial market of thatcountry. viii.) A healthy financial system is critical if growing economy isto attract foreign investment. At the heart of financial system isthe banking system. To prevent catas- trophes fromhappening countries like India need to take steps to ensurethat the banking system is adequately capitalized andregulatory regime of banking supervision is strong and welregulated. ix.) Following the advice of Feldstein (1998), a part of thereserves may be invested in higher-yield (higher-risk)securities [Feldstein considers traditional austerity mea- suresas sufficient to end the crisis in Indonesia. In parti- cular, hedenies the need for a comprehensive restruc- turing of theIndonesian economy to restore access to international capitamarkets. As safeguard against inapp- ropriate interferenceinto the domestic affairs of deve- loping countries, Feldsteinproposes three questions that the IMF should ask whendeciding whether to insist on a particular measure. Is thisreform really needed to restore the country’s access tointernational capital markets? Is this a technical matter thatdoes not interfere unnece- ssarily with the proper jurisdictionof a sovereign govern- ment? If the policies to be changed arealso practiced in the major industrial economies of Europe,would the IMF think it appropriate to force similar changes inthose countries if they were subject to a fund program?(Feldstein, 1998). Feldstein answers no to all three questions:the reforms are not needed to restore access to internationacapital markets; they interfere with Indonesia’s sovereignty;and the IMF is biased, pushing for structural reforms indeveloping countries without pro- moting similar measures inEurope]. x.) As India is not untouched by the wave of global financiaslowdown, there is need to create a stable finan- ciaenvironment. The key to stability is establishing a track recordof low inflation [Low inflation depends criti- cally on low moneysupply growth, which in turn depends on the public sector

Available online at www.ignited.in Page 16

E-Mail: ignitedmoffice@gmail.com

deficit being under control, and the government refusing to monetize short term capital inflows. If government fails to achieve this then excess money supply growth will fuel asset prices, boost the short term growth of economy but create a growing current account deficit, and finally cause inflation itself to rise], which in turn means a low fiscal deficit and mone- tary policy aimed at preventing credit expansion. Low inflation means low interest rates, better industrial rela- tions and more stable exchange rates. Foreign investors view low inflation as the bedrock on which to build a market economy. xi.) On the fiscal front, further consolidation remains important to sustain growth and manage financial globalization. Despite India's impressive revenue perfor- mance, fiscal consolidation has stalled and public debt remains high, squeezing the fiscal space needed for public investment in physical and social infrastructure. Both expenditure and revenue measures are needed, including rationalizing subsidies, cutting tax exemptions, enhancing tax administration, and broadening the tax base. A tighter fiscal stance could also limit the infla- tionary impact of capital inflows. xii.) Sound reserve management practices are important for the developing countries like India because they can increase a country's or region's overall resilience to shocks. Through their interaction with financial markets, reserve managers gain access to valuable information that keeps policy makers informed of market develop- ments and views on potential threats. The importance of sound practices has also been highlighted by expe- riences where weak or risky reserve management prac- tices have restricted the ability of the authorities to res- pond effectively to financial crises, which may have accentuated the severity of these crises. Moreover, weak or risky reserve management practices can also have significant financial and reputational costs. Several coun- tries, for example, have incurred large losses that have had direct, or indirect, fiscal consequences. Accordingly, appropriate portfolio management policies concerning the currency composition, choice of investment instruments, and acceptable duration of the reserves portfolio, and which reflect a country's specific policy settings and cir- cumstances, serve to ensure that assets are safeguard- ded, readily available and support market confidence. Sound reserve management policies and practices can support, but not substitute for, sound macroeconomic management. Moreover, inappropriate economic policies (fiscal, monetary and exchange rate, and financial) can pose serious risks to the ability to managereserves. Last but not the least, international experience shows that themore open the country’s capital account and the more volatilethe capital flows in the global economy, the more binding isthe constraint on national policymakers (see what happenedwith policymakers in Southeast Asian countries in the 1997financial crisis as currencies collapsed on the back of massivecapital outflows [The Asian currency crisis was originated inthe private sector. Among others, the most critical factorswere over- expansion of corporate credit with un-hedgedshort-term borrowing from abroad; large amounts ofunproductive capital investments; and speculation onovervalued assets and large trade deficits. July 2, 1997marked the devaluation of the Thailand baht, triggered by aseries of banking bail-outs by the central government. Thecentral bank was forced to mobilize its resources to cover forexcessive property lending by commercial banks. The increasing financial pressure stemming from the country'sexceptional infrastructure building programs had finallydamaged confidence in the baht. The IMF moved in with a$17.2 billion rescue program. The danger was that withThailand's currency crashing against the dollar, the rest of therapidly growing Asian tigers would also be affected. FollowingThailand's baht, Malaysia, Indonesia and the Philippinescurrencies all were hit as well. Furthermore, even SouthKorea and Taiwan were affected. The per- ception is that the'new tiger' economies are financially overleveraged. Inactuality, starting in 1996, a mix of domestic and externashocks revealed weaknesses in the Thai economy that untithen had been masked by their rapid economic growth andthe weakness of the US dollar to which the Thai currency waspegged. To an extent, Thailand's difficulties resulted from itsearlier economic success. Strong growth and generallyprudent macroeconomic policy had attracted large capitainflows, much of them short-term and many of them attractedby the establishment of the Bangkok International BankingFacility in 1993. While these inflows had permitted fastergrowth, they had also allowed domestic banks to rapidlyexpand lending, generating imprudent investments andunrealistic increases in asset prices. Past success also mayhave contributed to a sense of ignorance by the Thaauthorities about the seriousness of Thailand' problems andthe need for policy action. Finally, without the con-vincingpolicy action and after a desperate defense of the currency bythe central bank, the crisis broke]). The impossibility of thistrinity [A key insight of open economy macroeconomics, which

Available online at www.ignited.in Page 17

E-Mail: ignitedmoffice@gmail.com

has come to prominence in recent decades, has been the idea of the ‘impossible trinity’ (Mundell, 1961)] stems from the fact that if CAC (Capital Account Convertibility) is accepted, according to theory, you either have the choice of giving up monetary independence or giving up the stable currency objective and letting the exchange rate float freely so that monetary policy can then be directed to inflation control. There is another related issue of whether CAC [In the buoyant situation that India currency finds itself, it is quite likely that residents will take on foreign currency dominated liabilities. Indeed, it would be a surprise and counter to the interest party condition, if liability dollarization did not happen. The future consequences will depend on risk management practices in the private sector. The more sophisticated these are, the more likely that companies will hedge some or all of their foreign currency exposure. In this case, there might be fewer risks associated with CAC] will lead to the type of dollarization [Since the abandonment of the gold standard at the outbreak of World War I and the Bretton Woods Conference following World War 2, some countries have been desperately seeking ways to promote global economic stability and hence their own prosperity. For the majority of these countries, the optimal way to obtain currency stability has been to peg the local currency to a major convertible currency. However, another option is to abandon the local currency in favor of the exclusive use of the U.S. dollar (or another major international currency, such as the euro). This is known as 'full dollarization'] that could blunt the exchange rate as an effective instrument to boost demand and tradable sector. Some experts (Subramanian, 2008) argued that India, which has had a flexible exchange rate for much of its history, can continue to have monetary independence even with CAC. But the problem will arise when there are significant upward pressures on exchange rate as a result of capital inflows. In this case, government might want to resist this pressure for the sake of preventing undue pressures on the tradable sector. In other words, it might de facto want to maintain a fixed or a semi fixed exchange rate, and the trilemma [This suggests that greater exchange rate flexi- bility need per se address the problem of capital flow induced threats to the competitiveness] (impossible trinity) will then bite. India has a managed float with no fixed rate targets for rupee movements. Daily movements are, however, watched very closely by the RBI. Our markets are relatively thin and the declared policy of the RBI is to meet temporary demand supply imbalances that arrive from time to time. The RBI’s objective is also to keep market movements orderly and ensure that there is no liquidity problem or rumour or panic induced volatility. Insuch a case, whether to go for full convertibility makes sensefor an emerging market like India is a case that requiresdeeper discussion. However, we still believe that the partiamove towards full convertibility on the capital account is a stepin the right direction towards aligning with the globalizationmantra that we have practiced so closely. But, once fulconvertibility is achieved, investors in all asset classes (debt,equity, real estate) might have to bear additional bouts ofvolatility as the Indian currency will then be more aligned tothe world financial markets and thus be more prone to ‘jerksin the global system. Conclusion Foreign capital has a key role to play in the economicdevelopment of India. Indian government has been con-tinuously proceeding for economic reforms and is quietassured to secure legislation to allow more foreign investmentin various sectors. The size of net capital inflows to India hasincreased significantly in the post reform period. Totaforeign investments into India in 2007-08 stood at US$59288 million (about Rs 2.5 lakh crore), up by a whopping162% over the previous year. October 2007 witnessed thehighest inflow - US $11591 million (Rs 48682 crore), CMIEdata shows. July, Sep- tember, December and January toowitnessed heavy investments and these months brought inabout 50% of the total inflows for 2007-08. Capital inflows,however, are not an unmitigated blessing. The managementof capital inflows is a complex process encompassing aspectrum of policy choices, which inter alia include: theappropriate level of reserves, monetary policy objectivesrelated to liquidity management and maintenance of healthfinancial market conditions with financial stability. Largecapital inflows often are associated with inflationarypressures, a real exchange rate appreciation, and dete-rioration in the current account. In addition, the history of LatinAmerica provides ample evidence that massive capital inflowsalso may contribute to stock market bubbles and lead to anexcessive expansion in domestic credit, jeopardizing thefinancial system's stability. Short term capital inflows intensifythese problems as the probability of an abrupt and suddenreversal increases. Not surprisingly, therefore, effectivebuttressing of these capital inflows is a key economic policyissue today. Countries with sound macroeconomic policiesand well- functioning institutions are in the best position toreap the benefits of capital flows and minimize the risks.India's inability to deal with capital inflows is partly a result of

Available online at www.ignited.in Page 18

E-Mail: ignitedmoffice@gmail.com

the government doing less of what it should do more of, and doing more of what it should do less of. There is precious little in terms of economic reforms, but the government has gone to great lengths to encourage more capital inflows. Of course, it is a different matter that it was totally overwhelmed when it got what it had wished for. It is important for the government to move forward by ade- quately preparing the economy for capital inflows. Not doing anything is not an option, and such an approach risks the government being blamed for spoiling the India story. Undertaking more economic reforms is not easy but has to be done: the government can either manage the process or competitive forces will bring it upon us in a lopsided manner. The ball is in the government's court. Countries that permit free capital flows must choose bet- ween the stability provided by fixed exchange rates and the flexibility afforded by an independent monetary policy.

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

While bearing full responsibility for any mistakes, I wish to thank Prof. L. N. Dahiya and Prof. S. D. Vashistha for reading the earlier versions of this paper and making a number of helpful comments and constructive criticisms. I also thank the comments and suggestions of anonymous referees, which were also of great assistance. However, I am alone responsible for all the remaining errors and inadequacy.

REFERENCES

Aghion P, Bacchetta P, Banerjee A (2001). “A corporate balance-sheet approach to currency crises”, J. Econ. Theory 119: 6-30. Arellano C, Mendoza E (2002). “Credit Frictions and Sudden Stops in Small Open economies: An Equilibrium Business Cycle Framework for Emerging Markets Crises”. NBER Working Paper 8880. Beer FM, Vaziri M (2004). “The federation of Euro-Asian stock exchanges: Returns distribution, volatilities and performance”. J. Am. Acad. Bus. 5: 276-285. Beladi H, Marjit S (1992).“Foreign Capital and Protectionism”, Can. J. Econ. 25: 233–38. Boskovska D (2006), “The Role of the Foreign Capital in the Integration Process of Republic of Macedonia”, The Amfiteatru Econ. J. 8:114- 121. Buiter WH, Patel UR (2006). “Excessive Budget Deficits, A Government Abused Financial System and Fiscal Rule”, India Policy Forum, 2:1- 38. Caballero R (2000). “Macroeconomic Volatility in Latin America: A View and Three Case Studies”, Economia, 1: 31-108. Calvo G, Reinhart C (2000). “When capital inflows come to a sudden stop: consequences and policy options”, in: Kenen, P.,Swoboda, A.(Eds.), Reforming the International Monetary andFinancial System. The International Monetary Fund, WashingtonDC. Calvo G, Leiderman L, Carmen RM (1994), “The Capital InflowsProblem: Concept and Issues”, Contemporary Economic Policy. 12:112-132. Chakraborthy C, Peter N (2008). “Economic Reforms, FDI andEconomic Growth in India: A Sector Level Analysis”, World Dev. 36:1192-1213. Chakraborty I (2001). “Economic Reforms, Capital Inflows andMacro Economic Impact in India”, CDS Working Paper 311: 123-32. Chao C, Yu E (1994a). “Foreign Capital Inflows and Welfare inan Economy with Imperfect Competition”, J. Dev. Econ. 45: 141–54.Chao C, Yu E (1995). “Export Share Requirements and Welfare inLDCs: A Three-sector General Equilibrium Analysis”, J. Int. Trade.Dev. 3: 33-45. Dasgupta D, Ratha D (2000). “What Factors Appear to Drive PrivateCapital Flows to Developing Countries? And How Does OfficiaLending Respond?”, Policy Research Working Paper No. 2932,World Bank, Washington, D.C. Dash R, Sumanjeet (2006). “Impact of Stock Market Reforms onLiquidity: Evidence from Bombay Stock Exchange”, J. Indian. Sch.Polit. Econ.15:124-45. Dash R, Sumanjeet (2008). “Explaining the Cross Section ofExpected Stock Return: An application of Fama and French Model inIndia”, Finance India, 22: 923-35. Edwards S (2004). “Financial Openness, Sudden Stops and theCurrent Account Reversal”, Ame. Econ. Rev. 94: 59-64. Ghose AK (2004). “Capital Inflows and Investment inDeveloping Countries”, Employment Strategy Paper,Employment Strategy Department, No 2004/11. Gopinath G (2004). ”Lending booms, sharp reversals and reaexchange rate dynamics” J. Int. Econ. 62: 1-23. Grenville SA (1998). “Capital Flows and Crisis”, Reserve Bankof Australia Bulletin December . pp. 16-31. Gupta P, Mishra D, Sahay R (2003). Output Response to Currencycrises. IMF Working Paper WP/03/230. Harris LE, Gurel E (1986). “Price and Volume Effects Associated withChanges in the S&P 500 List: New Evidence for the Existence ofPrice Pressures”. J. Financ. 4: 803-815. Henry PB (2000a). “Do stock market liberalizations causeinvestment booms?”. J. Financ. Econ. 58: 289-301. Hutchison M, Noy I ( 2002) “Output costs of currency and balance ofpayments crises in emerging markets”. Comparative Econ. Studies44: 27– 44. Hutchision M, Michael, Noy Ilan (2006). “Sudden Stops and MexicanWave: Currency Crises, Capital Flow Reversals and Output Loss inEmerging Markets”. J. Econ. Dept. 79: 225-248. Ito T (2006). “Sudden Stops in Capital Flows: When the CenterSpreads the Virus”, presented in the conference on ‘GlobaImbalances and Risk Management: Has the Center Become thePeriphery?’ Mardid, Spain, 16-17th May.

Available online at www.ignited.in Page 19

E-Mail: ignitedmoffice@gmail.com

Jalan B (1999). “International financial Architecture: Developing country’s Perspective”, RBI Bulletin. Jitter R (2003). “Sudden Stop in Capital Inflows and the Design of Exchange Rate Regime”, HWWA Discussion Paper No. 213, European Central Bank. Jobson JD, Korkie BM (1981). “Performance hypothesis testing with the Sharpe and Treynor measures”, J. Financ. 36: 877- 889. Jones RW (1984). ‘Protection and the Harmful Effects of Endogenous Capital Flows’, Econ. Lett. 15: 325–30. Kohli R (2003) “Capital Flows and Domestic Financial Sector in India”, Econ Pol. Wkly. Feb. 22: 761-68. Krugman P (1993). “International finance and economic development”, in A.Giovannini (ed.), Finance and development: issues and experience, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp. 11-24. Lensik R, Oliver M, Osei R (1999). “The Impact of Uncertain Capital Flows on Economic Growth in Developing Countries: An Empirical Analysis For the 1999’s”, Paper Presented in University of Groningen. Levin R (2001). “International financial liberalization and economic growth”, Rev. of Int. Econ. 9: 668-702. Marjit S, Beladi H (1996). “Protection and the Gainful Effects of Foreign Capital” . Econ. Lett. 53: 311-16. Marjit S, U Broll, S Mitra (1997). “Targeting Sectors for Foreign Capital Inflow in a Small Developing Economy”. Rev. Int. Econ. 5: 101-05